The University of Michigan
555 South Forest Street
Third Floor
Ann Arbor, MI 48104-2531
T 734-936-9842
F 734-998-6341
/
|
|
|
Q&A with Johnathan Gruber, Ph.D.
Jonathan Gruber, Professor of Economics
at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, has spent more than a decade
examining health insurance issues. Gruber, former Deputy Assistant Secretary
for Economic Policy at the U.S. Treasury Department, recently co-authored
the paper, “Subsidies to Employee Health Insurance Premiums and
the Health Insurance Market.” Gruber recently talked with ERIU about
the feasibility of targeting subsidies to induce uninsured workers to
take-up employer-sponsored health insurance.
Q-Do uninsured workers take up offers of employer-offer health
insurance when the cost is lowered for them through subsidies?
A-Previous literature has found that generally people don’t change
their minds. Previous research has compared firms with different levels
of employee contributions and found that take-up rates of those employer
offers are really very similar across firms with different levels of contributions.
Ebonya Washington and I focused on a particular segment of the population—those
who are offered health insurance—and the question is ‘Will
those who are offered health insurance but turn it down, will they change
their mind if the price changes?’
We examined the effect of the federal government’s introduction
of tax subsidies for employer-provided health insurance to its employees,
first for postal employees in 1994 and then for all other federal employees
in the year 2000. We looked at what happened to take-up rates among uninsured
federal workers and found, very much in line with the previous literature,
a close to zero effect on employees’ decisions to take up health
care coverage when there’s a change in the subsidization of health
care premiums.
Q-What was the effect of the subsidy – moving from a post-tax
to pre-tax treatment of premiums – for federal workers?
A-For a non-postal worker, the change took $500 to $1,000 off their health
insurance costs.
Q-Your paper concludes that the subsidy increases government’s
costs by about $700 million per year. And that led only 11,000 to 22,000
uninsured workers to take up coverage?
A-Right. About 7 percent to 8 percent of all federal employees are uninsured,
and this change essentially made no dent in that number. To spend $38,000
per newly insured on such an incredibly small number is really the worst
performance I’ve ever seen.
Q-What is the typical amount that policymakers figure or that researchers
model it will cost for each newly insured individual?
A-It very much depends on the policy. For policies that cover small numbers
of people, like 1 million or 2 million people, it typically costs around
$3,000 for each newly insured. Policies such as the Democratic presidential
candidates have proposed, which cover 25 or 30 million new people, typically
cost about $10,000 per newly insured. The more people you can cover the
more it costs. Again, to spend $38,000 per newly insured on such an incredibly
small number is really the worst performance I’ve ever seen.
Q-Put this in perspective, what does the Federal Employees’ Health
Benefits Plan spend on the typical federal worker?
A-The government today typically spends around $5,000 to $6,000 for a
family.
Q-What were those extra costs attributed to?
A-Essentially 99 percent of the effect of this policy was basically a
tax break for federal workers who were already insured.
Q-Do workers choose more or less expensive plans when offered a larger
subsidy?
A-What we found—and this is keeping up with the previous literature—is
that when you essentially lower the cost differential between more expensive
and less expensive plans, which is what this subsidy does, people choose
the more expensive plans. When the tax subsidy was in place you saw a
shift to taking up more expensive health insurance plans.
Q-Why is the use of subsidies so attractive to healthcare policymakers?
A-It’s tempting when looking at it superficially. A large number
of the uninsured, about one-quarter of the uninsured, are offered health
insurance. One might think it’s an easy-to-get group. They are already
in a context where health insurance is available, so subsidizing them
might lead some of them to take it up.
What that argument misses is the fact that while that is a large share
of the uninsured, it’s an incredibly small share of those who are
offered insurance. Only about 7 percent of those offered insurance are
uninsured. If you offer a subsidy to everyone who is offered health insurance,
for every 7 cents that goes to someone who is uninsured, 93 cents goes
to someone who is insured. So people are just thinking about it the wrong
way.
Another motivation for subsidies here is more legitimate—it’s
one of equity. These people say if we’re going to subsidize individuals
to have health insurance, we need to help those who are doing the right
things and buying health insurance through their employer—we’re
going to offer a subsidy to them too. I think a lot of the experts who
promote this understand it’s not a very efficient way to increase
health insurance coverage but they promote it more from an equity standpoint.
Q-Are there any cases where premium subsidies seem to be effective, like
in SCHIP?
A-In terms of subsidies to those already offered health insurance I see
no context for their effective policy. But there are other types of subsidies
that do work, such as offering subsidized buy-in rates to public insurance
for low-income populations. I don’t want to tar all subsidies with
one brush based on this research.
Q-How difficult is it to target employee premium subsidies? Why?
A-It’s incredibly difficult because the vast majority of those offered
health insurance take it up. Even if you look at those below the poverty
line, about 75 percent of people who are offered health insurance have
health insurance. And if you go to 100 to 200 percent of the poverty level,
about 85 percent of those offered health insurance have health insurance.
The bottom line seems to be if people are offered health insurance they,
by and large, take it. Either they take it or they take it through a spouse
who is offered. What policymakers need to aim toward, if they want to
promote private health insurance, is getting employers to offer insurance,
not getting employees to take up once they are offered.
Q-What is the message for policymakers?
A-They should look at this in the context of the literature that exists.
The bottom line is now you’ve got basically two different approaches
to try to answer this question: one is to look casually at firms with
different contribution rates; the other is to look more precisely at this
particular change for a specific population. Both ways you end up with
a similar answer: this is not a price responsive group. This is the final
nail in the coffin of the argument that we should be subsidizing this
population.
Q-What do you personally think are strategies policymakers should
consider to get the biggest bang for the buck in reducing the number of
uninsured?
A-That depends where you are on the budget constraint. If the goal is
to cover a modest number of people, like 5 million people, then I think
it’s unambiguous that the best thing to do is expand public health
insurance. That’s highly targeted and it really gets the groups
where the most uninsured reside. And in particular, I think the most efficient
thing you could do is expand public health insurance not to more children,
who are largely already eligible, but to uninsured adults who aren’t.
If you want to cover a bigger number, 20-plus million, then I think expanding
public health insurance alone won’t do it. You need some combination
of expanding public health insurance to low-income groups and allowing
people to buy into some kind of pooling mechanism for higher income groups.
Either buy into public insurance or buy into some state pool. That’s
what you need in order to get to the bigger numbers. This is the final
nail in the coffin of the argument that subsidizing premiums is an easy
way to increase coverage
Back to top
Funded by The Robert Wood Johnson Foundation, ERIU is
a five-year program shedding new light on the causes and consequences
of lack of coverage, and the crucial role that health insurance plays
in shaping the U.S. labor market. The Foundation does not endorse the
findings of this or other independent research projects.
|